Economic literature is unanimous in stating that several factors influence the flow of direct investments and immigration.1 These include tax policies, infrastructure, local markets, labor opportunities, and, mainly, the quality of life.
In a moment that the United States, the largest economy in the world, is supposed to implement a Copernican twist toward an internal tax policy focused on its own demands, why should other countries dismiss the possibility of implementing their own tax policies through the adoption of special tax regimes such as those to attract new residents?
The legal design of new residents’ tax regimes should focus on three pillars: constitutionalism, tax policy, and global tax avoidance rules. Those regimes encompass programs employed by countries to attract new taxpayers. Over the last few years, citizens of different nationalities have
been migrating, driven by distinct factors that include new residents’ tax regimes. This generally involves the grant of tax exemptions for both active and passive foreign income. The oldest and best-known program of this kind is the English non-dom regime, which is now semi-extinct.
It was based on the equation of new residents’ foreign income taxation as nonresidents.
Evidently, this kind of regime raises theoretical and practical questions about constitutional
power limitations, tax competition, and fairness. Although this topic may not seem novel in
terms of international taxation (for example, tie breaker rules in article 2 of the OECD model income tax treaty or exit tax rules), double taxation treaties were not designed to address this issue comprehensively. They are ill-equipped to manage this emerging global diaspora.
Post COVID-19 dynamics have amplified this paradox regarding new tax regimes for foreigners: While countries promote residency visas with new tax regimes, they simultaneously enforce stricter global antiavoidance rules, such as controlled foreign corporation legislation for individuals and exit tax mechanisms.
This scenario creates a new form of tax competition among countries. On the one hand,
some countries aim to attract individuals by exempting foreign income for new residents; on the other hand, large and developed economies strive to amplify their revenues, taxing nondistributed profits or gains from individuals, as well introducing new taxes on gross income and property. The question is whether there is a right or wrong approach from international tax law. The compatibility of these regimes with tax principles should be established case by case, through the evaluation of each country’s fiscal policies and not through a global approach made by international institutions.
National Tax Policies and Specific Tax Regimes
The relationship between national economic goals and new residents’ tax regimes is evident. No country will establish a special tax regime without a macroeconomic goal. Consider two examples: golden visa programs (for example, Greece) and programs designed to attract digital nomads and highly qualified professionals (for example, Spain). The first seeks to attract new taxpayers through foreign investments in the most attractive sector of the Greek economy, the real estate industry.
The second aims to attract new individual taxpayers to expand its tax base and social security contribution revenues.
The latter addresses Spain’s public pension deficit, one of the country’s main macroeconomic problems.
For this reason, all new tax residents must contribute to Spain’s social security system. Another example stems from two intersecting tax policy measures. Following Brazil’s 2013 tax amnesty act, many Brazilians migrated to Portugal, attracted by the nonhabitual resident (NHR) regime.
However, this kind of regime often raises conflicts with international anti-tax avoidance measures.
For example, there are tensions between Portugal’s NHR regime and local and European antiavoidance rules such as CFC legislation for individuals and exit tax mechanisms. Whereas the NHR regime is based on a single law, Portugal’s CFC framework is very complex. It encompasses jurisdictional, transactional, and conceptual approaches, adding significant complexity and leading to legal disputes arising from antinomies, confronting criteria such as lex specialis versus lex generalis and international versus national law.
Regional Conflicts and Global Dynamics
The overlap between national and international legislation regarding individual tax regimes is even more problematic when it involves tax residency and so-called passive foreign investment companies.
It is one of the most sensitive issues when applied to new residents’ regimes because of the fact that it may confront different sets of antiavoidance rules. For instance, since 2021, some EU countries harmonized transparency regimes for individuals while implementing corporate-focused CFC directives. In attempting to curb the use of holding companies for individuals, the EU inadvertently created its own set of favorable regimes for personal foreign investment companies previously existent in some EU state members.
It has created new windows for disputes in the EU’s Court of Justice, through the legal conflicts that stem from the inability to enforce CFC rules when they conflict with EU foundational principles of free movement of capital and persons. Besides, the net of bilateral tax treaties is also more of a hindrance than a help.
Conventional rules either are inapplicable (for example, the incompatibility of CFC rules with treaties) or place foreign investments in discriminatory positions, challenging article 24 of the OECD model convention. This is evident in treaties with dividend exemption clauses, especially given that some countries proficiently use tax and fiscal incentives as a way of bringing in foreign direct investment.
A Case-by-Case Perspective
Although new resident regimes aspire to legitimacy, they face pushbacks from hard and soft antiavoidance rules. In turn, there is a battle between principles of fairness and constitutional supremacy to implement tax incentives. In fact, there are other relevant elements at play when someone thinks about moving to another country.
Many of the jurisdictions that offer new residents’ regimes can provide a good quality and low cost of living, pleasant weather, good infrastructure, and a convenient geographical location. Therefore, this preexisting ecosystem can be a pillar to implement tax-base-shifting policies, which are in general a non-tax erosion measure.
In this context a new residents’ tax regime can be a wise choice for a country to attract skilled professionals and new contributors to their social security system.
New residents’ regimes can create tax loopholes, avoidance, and inequality, but this can be controlled by a dynamic review of the rules, like exit tax mechanisms (for example, the oneyear rule for capital gains taxation in the Italian regime). From another angle, the assumption that new residents’ tax regimes are always addressed to ultrawealthy individuals is incorrect.
For example, many of those who adhered to Portugal’s NHR regime were middle-income individuals seeking to reside in a quiet place with a low cost of living. In summary there isn’t a one-size-fits-all
answer to whether new residents’ tax regimes are good or bad.
From an individual standpoint, the right to freedom includes legitimate aspirations to change residence, considering the tax burden. In this vein, we all know that international tax law should respect constitutional national rules.
We’re living in a moment in which the speech from international institutions of the necessity of tax system’s standardization in the name of fairness is now being questioned. Countries have different characteristics and opportunities in terms of howmto increase the number of taxpayers, new contributors to support their social security systems, and so on. Conclusively, international tax law,
constitutional tax powers of countries, individuals’ freedom of movement, and fairness should be balanced for each situation regarding a new residents’ tax regime.
Text originally published on Tax Notes.